字幕列表 影片播放
The following content is provided under a Creative
Commons license.
Your support will help MIT OpenCourseWare continue to
offer high quality educational resources for free.
To make a donation or view additional materials from
hundreds of MIT courses, visit MIT OpenCourseWare at
ocw.mit.edu.
PROFESSOR: So what I want to do today is I want to talk
about what the heck this course is.
What is microeconomics?
What are you going to be learning in this course?
And just, sort of, set us up for the semester.
OK.
So basically, microeconomics is all about scarcity.
It's all about how individuals and firms make decisions given
that we live in a world of scarcity.
Scarcity is key because basically what we're going to
learn about this semester in various shapes and forms is a
lot of different types of constrained optimization.
We're going to learn a lot about different ways that
individuals make choices in a world of scarcity.
OK?
That is, this course is going to be about trade-offs.
Given scarce resources, how the individuals and firms
trade off different alternatives to make
themselves as well-off as possible.
That's why economics is called the dismal science.
OK?
It's called the dismal science because we are not about
everyone have everything.
We're always the people who say, no, you can't have
everything.
You have to make a trade-off.
OK?
You have to give up x to get y.
And that's why people don't like us.
OK?
Because that's why we're called the dismal science,
because we're always pointing out the
trade-offs that people face.
Now, some may call it dismal, but I call it fun.
And that may be because of my MIT training, as I said I was
an undergraduate here.
In fact, MIT is the perfect place to teach microeconomics
because this whole institute is about engineering solutions
which are really ultimately about constrained
optimization.
Indeed, what's the best example in the
world we have of this?
It's the 270 contest. Right?
You're given a pile of junk, you've got to build something
that does something else.
That's an exercise in constrained optimization.
All engineering is really constrained optimization.
How do you take the resources you're given and do the best
job building something.
And that's really what microeconomics is.
Just like 270 is not a dismal contest, microeconomics is not
to me a dismal science.
You could think of this course like 270.
But instead of the building robots, we're
running people's lives.
OK?
That's, kind of, the way I like to
think about this course.
Instead of trying to decide how we can build something to
move a ping pong ball across a table, we're trying to decide
how people make their decisions to consume, and
firms make their decisions to produce.
That's basically what's going to go on in this class.
OK?
And that's why basically modern microeconomics was
founded at MIT in the 1950s by Paul Samuelson.
The father of modern economics was a professor here, and he
basically founded the field.
He basically introduced mathematics to economics.
And through teaching this course, 14.01, 50, 60 years
ago, actually developed the field that we now study.
Now, what we're going to do in this class, is focused on two
types of actors in the economy:
consumers and producers.
OK?
And we are going to build models of how consumers and
producers behave. Now, technically, a model is going
to be a description of any relationship between two or
more economic variables.
OK?
That's a model.
A description of any relationship between two or
more economic variables.
The trick with economics, and the reason many of you will be
frustrated during the semester, is that unlike the
modern relationship between say energy and mass these
models are never precise.
They are never accurate to the 10th decimal.
OK?
This is not a precise, scientific
relationship with modeling.
We'll be making a number of simplifying assumptions that
allow us to capture the main tendencies in the data.
That allow us to capture the main insights into how
individuals make consumption decisions and how firms make
production decisions.
But it's not going to be as clean and precise as the kind
of proofs you're going to be doing in some of your other
classes in freshman and sophomore year.
OK?
So basically, we have a trade off with the simplifying
assumptions.
On the one hand, obviously we want a model that can explain
reality as much as possible.
If a model can't explain reality, it's not useful.
On the other hand, we need a model that's tractable, a
model that I can teach you in a lecture or less.
OK?
And basically, what we do is we make a lot of simplifying
assumptions in this class to make those models work.
And yet, what we'll find is despite these assumptions,
we'll come up with incredibly powerful predictions of how
consumers and producers behave.
So with consumers what we're going to do is, we're going to
say that consumers are constrained by their limited
wealth or what we'll call their budget constraint.
And subject to that constraint they choose the set of goods
that makes them as well off as possible.
OK?
That's what we're going to call utility maximization.
We'll say the consumers maximize their utility,
consumers are going to maximize utility subject to a
budget constraint.
That's going to be what we're going to develop
the consumer decision.
They have some utility function which is going to be
a model of their preferences.
OK?
So I'm going to propose to take everything you love in
life and write it down as a u function.
OK?
Then I'm going to propose you take all the resources at your
disposal, write them down as a budget constraint and then I
just do constrained maximization to solve for how
you make decisions.
Firms, on the other hand, are going to maximize profits.
Pi is profits.
Firms are going to maximize profits.
Their goal is to make as much profit as possible, to earn as
much money as possible.
OK?
However, that's going to be subject to both the demands of
consumers, we get to firms it's a lot harder, subject to
both consumer demand and input costs.
So firms have to consider, consumers have to consider
look what does stuff cost and what do I like,
I'll make my decision.
Firms is a little more complicated.
They've go to consider, what do consumers want and how do I
make what they want?
So they've got to consider both the output side, what a
consumer is going to want me to make and what's it going to
cost me to produce that good?
And how do I combine those to make the most profits?
OK?
So from these assumptions, we will be able to answer the
three fundamental questions of microeconomics.
OK?
The three fundamental questions of microeconomics
will be, what goods and services should be produced?
What goods and services should be produced?
How to produce those goods and services?
And who gets the goods and services?
What goods and services get produced?
How to produce those goods and services?
And who gets them?
And what's amazing, we'll learn in this course, is that
all three of these questions, the three fundamental
questions that drive our entire economy, are all solved
through the role of one key state
variable, which is prices.
Prices in the economy resolve all of these problems. OK?
Consumers and firms will interact in a market, they'll
interact in a marketplace.
And out of that marketplace will emerge a set of prices,
in a way we'll describe.
And those prices will allow firms and consumers to make
the relevant decisions.
OK?
So let me just give you one, and we're going to do all this
rigorously throughout the semester, let me just start
with one casual example.
OK?
Let's think about the development of the iPod.
OK?
Let's cast our minds way back, lo way back to the development
of the iPod.
OK?
Now, when Apple was thinking about making the iPod, they
had to ask, would consumers want this?
So consumers had to decide given their limited resources,
given the fact that they were buying a certain set of things
would they be willing to forsake some things they were
already doing to spend the money on the iPod?
OK?
It was a non-trivial amount of money.
Would they be willing to forsake things they are
already doing?
OK?
To spend money on the iPod.
And clearly they were.
Clearly, consumers were willing to spend money, to
spend a lot of money, to get an iPod.
They were originally what? $300 Back
when $300 meant something.
OK.
So basically, what the firm will do is they'll say, OK, we
get a signal from the consumer that they're willing to pay
money to get the iPod.
They're willing to pay a high price to get the iPod.
Now, the firm will say, well, should we make iPods?
Well, that will depend on what it cost to make them.
So we have to then assess what are the inputs that we'll need
to make an iPod?
Well, to do that we have to look at the prices of the
various inputs that we'll need, of the chip in them and
the metal and all the other stuff that goes into the iPod.
OK?
So they can shop across different countries, to
different kinds of chips, they can look at different kinds of
monitors, et cetera.
But, once again, what they'll do is they'll use the prices
of those different inputs to decide how
to produce the iPod.
So whether to produce the iPod will depend on the price
people are willing to pay for it.
How to make the iPod will depend on the prices that
firms have to pay for the chip and the casing and all the
other things that go into the iPod.
OK?
And then finally, who's going to get the iPod?
Well, they're going to make a certain amount.
What decided who gets them?
Well, the person who gets them are the people who are willing
to pay the price that Apple decides to charge.
Some people are willing to pay that price, they're going to
get an iPod.
Some people are not willing to pay that price, they will not
get an iPod.
So the price in the market will ultimately decide who
gets the iPod, as well.
OK?
So basically, prices will determine what gets produced,
how it's produced, and who gets the
goods that are produced.
OK?
Of course, this is a very, very simplified example, as
you can already tell.
There are lots of cases where prices don't
decide these things.
So my favorite example is the fact that there are lines for
hours to get tickets to see a Lady Gaga concert.
OK?
Now if it's really true that prices determine everything,
we shouldn't see any lines.
It should just be that those who are willing to pay the
most to see Lady Gaga should.
Those who want the most to get Lady Gaga
should get the tickets.
Those who aren't willing to pay shouldn't get the tickets.
Why should there be a line?
Not to mention the fact that people shouldn't be willing to
pay anything, but that's a different issue.
That's a taste issue.
We'll come to taste later.
OK?
So basically, clearly this is not working perfectly.
If the world worked in the way I just described, then what
should happen is there should be essentially an auction and
whoever is willing to pay the most for Lady Gaga tickets
would get them.
And whoever is not willing to pay wouldn't.
It wouldn't involve any waiting in
line or other things.
Now, what's very interesting is we've actually seen an
evolution from my youth to your youth towards the
economic model.
When I was a kid, if you wanted, so then it was Cars
tickets, OK, to date myself, OK, you had to go and camp out
at 3:00 in the morning outside the store where they're
selling them to get the tickets.
Now, of course, you don't do that anymore.
Now you go on Stub Hub or Ticketmaster or these other
secondary sellers and there there are prices that
determine it.
So how many people have waited on line to
get a concert ticket?
That's amazing.
So if I asked this question 30 years ago, 90% of the hands
would have gone up.
OK?
So what that means is the price mechanism has
started to be used.
It has replaced the line mechanism as a way to allocate
those tickets.
And we see prices working.
That wasn't true.
There wasn't StubHub.
There weren't these secondary ticket sellers 30 years ago.
You had to wait on line to get the tickets.
Now, so that's basically, sort of, an overview about, sort of
an example, of how we think about the role of prices.
Now, let me draw a couple of important distinctions, terms
I'm going to use this semester that I want you to be
comfortable with.
OK?
The first distinction I want to draw is between theoretical
versus empirical economics.
Theoretical versus empirical economics.
OK.
Theoretical economics is the process of building models to
explain the world.
OK?
Empirical economics is the process of testing those
models to see how good a job they do in
explaining the world.
OK?
We could all make up a model.
OK?
Anybody with math skills could make up a model.
But it doesn't do any good unless it's actually doing
something to explain the world.
And so basically, the goal of theoretical economics is
essentially to build a model that has some testable
predictions.
To build a model that says, look here's my simplified
model of how consumers decide whether or not to buy an iPod.
OK?
I have a model of that, that I've built theoretically.
Well, that has some testable predictions.
And the role of empirical economics is to gather the
data and go and test them using statistical methods.
Specifically, typically regression analysis like the
kind you learn about in advanced statistics.
OK?
So basically, what we're going to do is we're going to is 95%
of this course will be about theoretical
economics this semester.
It will be about understanding how economists develop the
models to model how consumers and firms behave. But I will
try to talk somewhat about empirical economics and what
data we can bring to bear to understand whether or not
these models explain the world.
OK?
The other distinction that's very important is positive
versus normative economics.
Positive versus normative economics.
And this is the distinction between the way things are,
which is positive economics, and the way things should be
which is normative economics.
Distinction between the way things are and the way
things should be.
OK?
So let's consider a great example of microeconomics at
work which is auctions on eBay.
OK?
Auctions on eBay, economists love studying auctions on eBay
because it's a textbook example of what we call a
perfectly competitive market which is what we'll focus on
the semester.
A perfectly competitive market.
OK?
And by that we mean that basically that producers in
this market offer up their good to a
wide range of consumers.
OK?
A number of producers offer up their goods to a
wide range of consumers.
OK?
And the consumers bid up the price until the person who has
the highest value for the good gets it.
So price serves exactly the signal it should
in allocating goods.
OK?
So really eBay's really sort of about this third thing of
who gets the good.
OK?
I offer my alarm clock or whatever on eBay, OK, and then
people bid on that.
And whoever values that the most, that rare Jon Gruber
alarm clock the most, they get it.
OK?
So it's a perfect textbook example.
OK?
And basically, because on eBay the price is used, or now with
also StubHub and concert tickets, the price is used to
allocate the good to the person who wants
it the most. OK?
Now, a recent example of an auction on eBay that a lot of
attention, not so recent anymore a couple years ago,
someone tried to auction their kidney on eBay.
OK?
Someone offered their kidney for auction on eBay and said,
I have two kidneys I only need one.
So I'm going to auction my kidney, you pay for me to fly
to wherever you need my kidney and the operation, they take
it out and they give it to you.
And that's the way it goes.
So what happened was person offered their kidney and they
said the starting price will be $25,000.
They didn't do a buy it now.
They said the starting price will be $25,000 and the
bidding went on.
The price got to $5 million before eBay shot it down.
eBay shut the auction down.
And eBay said no, in fact, you can't do this.
Now there's two questions here.
The first is, why did the price of the
kidney go so high?
That's the positive question.
The positive question is, why did the price the kidney on
eBay get so high?
And here, we'll talk, and you'll learn more starting
Friday, about the twin forces of supply and demand.
The twin forces that drive the economy of supply and demand.
And you'll talk more rigorously
about these on Friday.
Basically, they're what they sound like.
Demand is how much someone wants something.
Supply is how much of it there is to have.
And the intuition here is surprising.
OK?
The more that there's demand for a good, the higher will be
the upward pressure on prices.
The more people want a good, the higher prices will go.
And the less supply there is of a good, also the higher
prices will go.
So if everybody wants something but it's common, the
price will be low.
And if no one wants something but it's uncommon, the price
will still be low, and vice versa.
In fact, the development of the model of supply and demand
framework was from Adam Smith, the, sort of, so-called first
economist who wrote The Wealth of Nations in 1776 which is,
sort of, viewed as the, kind of, first
serious book about economics.
And he posed what he called the water diamond paradox.
What Smith said in that book is, look, it's clear water is
the most important thing in life.
We can't live without water.
And diamonds are completely irrelevant to life.
You can live totally fine without a diamond.
And yet, the price of diamonds is
astronomical and water's free.
How can this be?
How can it be that water which is so much more of a
fundamental building block of our life is so much cheaper
than diamonds which are not.
And the answer, of course, is that so far you've only
considered demand and not supply.
Yes, it's true.
The demand for water is much higher than
the demand for diamonds.
But the supply is even larger.
So that basically, yes it's true that while water should
be worth more, in fact, in the end the price of water is much
lower, because of the twin forces of demand and supply.
The demand is higher, but the supply is much higher.
So the price ends up lower.
And that was his diamond water paradox.
OK?
Well, in this case, it's a similar thing.
What determines the demand for a kidney?
What determines the demand for a kidney is going to be the
fact that you die without it.
OK?
If you have no kidneys, you're having kidney failure.
OK?
You'll die without it.
So basically, what will determine it is people are
willing to spend all their wealth, as much money as they
can have, to get a kidney OK?
So the demand will be quite high.
The supply will be quite low.
Sadly, not many people are willing to be organ donors.
More relevantly, a lot of people aren't in good
situations to be organ donors.
OK?
As a result, the supply is much lower than the demand.
So we have a situation with a high demand, a low supply and
the price went through the roof.
That's a positive analysis.
OK?
So we can understand pretty intuitively.
We don't need this course to understand why
the price went up.
OK?
It's just the twin powers of demand and supply.
But what about the normative question which is, should eBay
have allowed this sale to happen?
EBay at $5 million cut it off and then passed the rule
saying you can't auction your body parts on eBay.
OK?
Should they have done that?
That's the normative question.
That's economics gets really interesting, which is you all
are smart enough to figure out why the price went up.
But this is where it gets interesting is should people
have been able to auction their kidney on eBay?
On the one hand, many, many people in this country die for
want of a body part.
OK?
Thousands to hundreds of thousands of people die every
year waiting for a transplant.
OK?
If someone is incredibly rich and they want a body part,
which to me a surplus because I have two kidneys, why
shouldn't they be allowed to buy it from me?
I'm better off because they can pay me a ton of money.
They are better off because they live.
So I've just described a transaction that makes both
parties better off.
Why shouldn't that be allowed to happen?
So you tell me.
Does everyone think eBay was wrong?
Yeah, go ahead.
AUDIENCE: Say there is another person who doesn't have as
much money, and that person also dies.
PROFESSOR: You mean the person who, what do you mean the
person doesn't have as much-
AUDIENCE: --so obviously somebody
doesn't get the kidney.
PROFESSOR: So in other words, what you're assuming is, let's
say that if I hadn't done the auction on eBay, I would have
just given my kidney away to the transplant center.
Then that's one less kidney that can go to
the transplant center.
And that means the rich guy gets the kidney, and someone
else implicitly doesn't.
That's a trade-off.
You've just described a trade-off.
The trade-off is that basically now we've allocated
the kidney away from the poor person to the rich person.
Now, but why do we care about that?
I mean one person dies, another person
lives, why do we care?
Yeah?
AUDIENCE: There would be some sort of case
of severity in condition.
Like there might be someone who's poor who would get the
kidney if it went to a transplant association because
they would die in a couple of days without it.
Whereas the rich person might just be able to afford it, and
it might make their life more convenient.
But they might not be in any more peril.
PROFESSOR: They might be a collector.
So basically, that's right.
So one reason we might care is because we think that kidneys
should be allocated on the basis of who needs
it the most. OK?
So a great example of this, of course, was Mickey Mantle with
a liver transplant.
Mickey Mantle, famous ballplayer, raging alcoholic,
who had liver failure because he was basically drinking
himself to death, and jumped the queue and got a liver
above a bunch, a lot of people and then he kept drinking and
killed himself and wasted the liver he'd gotten.
OK?
So basically, you can think that doesn't make sense.
We should give it to people who need it the most. For who
it would do the most good in terms of
increasing their life.
OK.
So we've got the substitution point.
OK.
Let's come back to the substitution point though.
Tell me a situation in which that's wrong.
Can someone tell me a situation in which, in fact,
that not a valid point.
Yeah.
AUDIENCE: Well, if the guy is only going to sell it.
He's not going to give it away.
PROFESSOR: Exactly.
You're assuming that the guy who did sell
would give it away.
But, in fact, if it's sell it or keep it
then there's no trade-off.
And similar here, if it's sell it or keep it then you might
as well let the rich guy get it.
Or is there another argument?
Is there another reason why you might not
want this to happen?
Yeah.
AUDIENCE: It would encourage people to use illegal ways of
getting kidneys.
PROFESSOR: So the other reason could be that we don't trust
people to make good decisions when money's involved.
That we think that, gee, if it's really true I can get a
couple million bucks for a kidney, I might give mine up
even if I haven't really thought through the
ramifications of doing so.
Even if there's a risk to the surgery, if there's a risk
that my other kidney will then fail then I'll be screwed.
OK?
So basically, we might have a paternalistic attitude that
will lead us to not want to allow people to engage in this
kind of risky behavior.
Yeah?
AUDIENCE: There may also be some legal ramifications
associated with that if someone sells their kidney and
then their other kidney fails, they might then blame eBay.
PROFESSOR: Want it back.
Like that Repo movie.
That's right.
There could, but let's leave the lawyers out of this, OK?
I don't like lawyers.
I'm going to rag on lawyers this semester.
We're going leave the lawyers out of this.
But, in any case, you're right.
That's, sort of, a
ramification of the same thing.
So we've talked about the fact that there's substitution.
We've talked about the fact that it's not allocated to
those who need it the most. We've talked about the fact
that people might be making bad decisions in doing this.
But there's another factor, as well, which is we may just as
a society feel it's unfair that rich people can get
things poor people can't.
There may be a pure equity component here.
OK?
Which is simply that we as a society value equality, value
income inequality.
And we think people should not have an extra shot at getting
a resource just because they're rich.
Now that is a very deep and hard concept, and we'll spend
a couple lectures talking about equity towards the end
of the semester.
By and large, we won't consider it.
OK?
But it turns out to be behind much of what we'll discuss,
OK, in much of what we'll discuss this semester and much
of what goes on in economics.
OK?
Just take a look at the debate that's going on right now in
terms of President Obama trying to decide whether or
not to extend tax cuts to wealthy individuals in the US.
Some people argue that allowing those tax cuts would
promote the economy.
OK?
But others argue it's unfair for rich
people to get tax breaks.
And that fairness argument matters a lot in terms of
driving the kind of economic policy
decisions we need to make.
So this semester, we're going to focus a lot on efficiency
and optimization and how to get resources
to the right place.
But you have to remember behind a lot of this is deep
normative issues about what should be happening, how
should an economy function, and, in particular, how should
we think about these kind of equity
issues that are so important.
OK.
The last thing I want to talk about is I want to talk about
why micro is not just an abstract concept for things
like you might say, oh this is all pretty funny and it's like
selling kidneys on eBay and tax cuts for the rich
and why do I care?
OK?
Well, you care because literally every decision you
make is made through the kind of framework we're going to
think about this semester.
OK?
Now, different decisions may follow our models more closely
and less closely.
But there is not an economic decision.
OK?
Sorry, let me back up.
There's not a decision that people have made that
economists haven't tried to model.
From whether to produce iPods, to how many times to
have sex each week.
OK?
These are all things economists have tried to model
with varying degrees of success.
OK?
Because economists think that these all come from the same
decision theoretic framework that we can discuss.
Let's talk about a simple example from this course.
Your decision of whether or not to buy the textbook.
There's a textbook and what's it cost? $140?
What's it cost?
Does anyone know?
AUDIENCE: This line says $180.
And this one says $180, but it's available for $130.
PROFESSOR: $130, fine.
So $130 for Professor Perloff out at Berkeley.
He doesn't get it all.
I wrote a textbook too.
He gets a small share of it.
OK.
So you have to decide, now has anyone bought a used version
of the fourth, well it's the fifth edition now, does
anybody use a version of the fourth edition?
Does anyone know what the used price is?
You can be honest. I don't care.
AUDIENCE: I know some people found it for like $85 or so.
PROFESSOR: So $85.
So you've got to decide.
So let's say you can buy the previous edition, the fourth
edition, for $85 or the current edition for $130.
OK?
You've got to make that decision.
OK?
How do you make that decision.
Well you may think, gee I just make the decision.
It's not really about microeconomics.
But it is.
We're going to model how you think about a
decision like that.
Well how do you think about a decision like that?
Well, the first thing you consider is your preferences.
How much are you willing to take a chance that there's new
stuff in the fifth edition that you need to know?
OK?
If the fifth issue was identical to the fourth
edition then you'd be an idiot to not just buy the used
fourth edition.
But it's not.
Textbook writers are smart.
They update their book.
OK?
So basically, the fifth edition is updated.
There's new things in it.
So you have to ask yourself, what are the odds that I need
some of the new information in the fifth edition and not in
the fourth edition?
And in thinking about that, you're going to think about
your preferences.
In particular, are you very risk averse, are you afraid to
take a chance?
Or are you risk loving?
Are you willing to take a chance?
OK?
That's one side of the equation.
If you're someone that says, you know I will not take a
chance in life.
I just have to make sure I learn the most possible from
this course.
Then you're going to want that new edition.
If you're someone that says, you know what screw it, I'll
just figure it out later.
I'm going to the lectures.
I don't care.
OK?
Then you might not want it that much.
So that's the first factor, is going to be your preferences
and break down how much you are willing to take a risk
that you need this fifth edition.
The second factor is going to be your constraint: how much
money you have. OK.
The more money you have, the more you're willing, or more
relevant perhaps your parents have, the more willing you are
to go ahead and buy that new edition.
The less money you have, the less willing you are.
OK?
So basically, it's going to depend on whether you're
paying or your parents are paying, in which case what the
hell you might as well buy the fifth edition.
OK?
And then finally, you're going to take these preferences and
this constraint, your preferences and your
resources, and go to the market and look at what does
the market tell me the difference is.
So you're going to say, here's how much I kind of care about
fifth versus fourth edition, here's the resources I have,
now I'll go to the market and say, aha there is a $45
difference between these two editions.
So now I will solve that constrained
optimization problem.
And I'll decide whether I want to get that book.
You are going to be thinking to yourself, this is stupid.
I never think about it that way.
But the key point is you don't have to think about it
exactly that way.
There's a famous example in economics of what's called the
as if principle.
I don't know if kids still say this one, as if.
So it's the as if principle.
OK?
And basically it's from Milton Friedman, the famous economist
from Chicago, who said, look, when you're playing pool,
technically you could compute the optimal angles of which to
shoot the ball every single time to get the appropriate
bounce and get the balls in.
You could do the mathematics and compute it.
But professional pool players are not in this class with
you, I'll only say that.
OK?
They're not guys who are able to do that computation.
They just know how to hit the ball to get the same outcome
they would get if they mathematically solved for the
optimal trajectory to hit the ball.
OK?
They behave as if they've solved the constrained
optimization problem.
And your decision when you buy this book, you may not think
it through the very framework that I just laid out very
heuristically and will lay out more rigorously this semester.
But you're going to behave as if you do.
Because those facts are going to be in your mind, and you'll
be thinking about it when you make that decision.
So while you may feel the models we learn in this course
are rather abstract and don't really explain how you behave
in an everyday basis, you're going to behave as if those
models are really applying to you.
And if you think about, over the next few days, think about
the decisions you make.
From should I bring an umbrella today,
it looks like rain?
Well, on the one hand, I might lose it.
It's a pain to carry.
On the other hand, how much do I care about getting wet?
That's a constrained optimization decision.
To should I have an extra drink at a party Friday night?
On the one hand, that could have some pros and cons.
OK?
These are all decisions, constrained optimization
decisions, you're going to make.
They're going to affect your life.
And what we'll learn this semester is about how you make
them and how we model, how economists can use what we
learn about that to understand the function of the economy.
OK?
So I'm going to stop there.
One other announcement, there will, in general, be handouts
every lecture.
I'm not going to do PowerPoint.
I'm going to do handouts.
So when you come in every lecture, please look at the
back banister.
Though typically, not today.
But typically, they'll be handouts that you'll need to
follow along with in class.
So remember, go to section on Friday, first problems that
will be posted on Friday and it will be due in section the
Friday after.
And I'll see you all back here on Monday, next Monday.