字幕列表 影片播放
The Washington Consensus is a set of 10 economic policy prescriptions considered
to constitute the "standard" reform package promoted for crisis-wracked
developing countries by Washington, D.C.–based institutions such as the
International Monetary Fund, World Bank, and the US Treasury Department. It was
coined in 1989 by English economist John Williamson. The prescriptions
encompassed policies in such areas as macroeconomic stabilization, economic
opening with respect to both trade and investment, and the expansion of market
forces within the domestic economy. Subsequent to Williamson's use of the
terminology, and despite his emphatic opposition, the phrase Washington
Consensus has come to be used fairly widely in a second, broader sense, to
refer to a more general orientation towards a strongly market-based
approach. In emphasizing the magnitude of the difference between the two
alternative definitions, Williamson himself has argued that his ten
original, narrowly defined prescriptions have largely acquired the status of
"motherhood and apple pie", whereas the subsequent broader definition,
representing a form of neoliberal manifesto, "never enjoyed a consensus
[in Washington] or anywhere much else" and can reasonably be said to be dead.
Discussion of the Washington Consensus has long been contentious. Partly this
reflects a lack of agreement over what is meant by the term, in face of the
contrast between the broader and narrower definitions But there are also
substantive differences involved over the merits and consequences of the
various policy prescriptions involved. Some critics take issue, for example,
with the original Consensus's emphasis on the opening of developing countries
to global markets, and/or with what they see as an excessive focus on
strengthening the influence of domestic market forces, arguably at the expense
of key functions of the state. For other commentators the issue is more what is
missing, including such areas as institution-building and targeted
efforts to improve opportunities for the weakest in society. Despite these areas
of controversy, a number of developmental institutions and
economists would by now accept the more general proposition that strategies best
work if they are specifically designed to the certain circumstances of the
individual countries. History
= Original sense: Williamson's Ten Points =
The concept and name of the Washington Consensus were first presented in 1989
by John Williamson, an economist from the Institute for International
Economics, an international economic think tank based in Washington, D.C.
Williamson used the term to summarize commonly shared themes among policy
advice by Washington-based institutions at the time, such as the International
Monetary Fund, World Bank, and U.S. Treasury Department, which were believed
to be necessary for the recovery of countries in Latin America from the
economic and financial crises of the 1980s.
The consensus as originally stated by Williamson included ten broad sets of
relatively specific policy recommendations:
Fiscal policy discipline, with avoidance of large fiscal deficits relative to
GDP; Redirection of public spending from
subsidies toward broad-based provision of key pro-growth, pro-poor services
like primary education, primary health care and infrastructure investment;
Tax reform, broadening the tax base and adopting moderate marginal tax rates;
Interest rates that are market determined and positive in real terms;
Competitive exchange rates; Trade liberalization: liberalization of
imports, with particular emphasis on elimination of quantitative
restrictions; any trade protection to be provided by low and relatively uniform
tariffs; Liberalization of inward foreign direct
investment; Privatization of state enterprises;
Deregulation: abolition of regulations that impede market entry or restrict
competition, except for those justified on safety, environmental and consumer
protection grounds, and prudential oversight of financial institutions;
Legal security for property rights. = Origins of policy agenda =
Although Williamson's label of the Washington Consensus draws attention to
the role of the Washington-based agencies in promoting the above agenda,
a number of authors have stressed that Latin American policy-makers arrived at
their own packages of policy reforms primarily based on their own analysis of
their countries' situations. Thus, according to Joseph Stanislaw and Daniel
Yergin, authors of The Commanding Heights, the policy prescriptions
described in the Washington Consensus were "developed in Latin America, by
Latin Americans, in response to what was happening both within and outside the
region." Joseph Stiglitz has written that "the Washington Consensus policies
were designed to respond to the very real problems in Latin America and made
considerable sense". In view of the implication conveyed by the term
Washington Consensus that the policies were largely external in origin,
Stanislaw and Yergin report that the term's creator, John Williamson, has
"regretted the term ever since", stating "it is difficult to think of a less
diplomatic label." A 2010 paper by Nancy Birdsall, Augusto
de la Torre, and Felipe Valencia Caicedo likewise suggests that the policies in
the original consensus were largely a creation of Latin American politicians
and technocrats, with Williamson's role having been to gather the ten points in
one place for the first time, rather than to "create" the package of
policies. In Williamson's own words from 2002:
= Broad sense = Williamson recognizes that the term has
commonly been used with a different meaning from his original prescription;
he opposes the alternative use of the term, which became common after his
initial formulation, to cover a broader market fundamentalism or "neoliberal"
agenda. I of course never intended my term to
imply policies like capital account liberalization, monetarism, supply-side
economics, or a minimal state, which I think of as the quintessentially
neoliberal ideas. If that is how the term is interpreted, then we can all
enjoy its wake, although let us at least have the decency to recognize that these
ideas have rarely dominated thought in Washington and certainly never commanded
a consensus there or anywhere much else...
More specifically, Williamson argues that the first three of his ten
prescriptions are uncontroversial in the economic community, while recognizing
that the others have evoked some controversy. He argues that one of the
least controversial prescriptions, the redirection of spending to
infrastructure, health care, and education, has often been neglected. He
also argues that, while the prescriptions were focused on reducing
certain functions of government, they would also strengthen government's
ability to undertake other actions such as supporting education and health.
Williamson says that he does not endorse market fundamentalism, and believes that
the Consensus prescriptions, if implemented correctly, would benefit the
poor. In a book edited with Pedro-Pablo Kuczynski in 2003, Williamson laid out
an expanded reform agenda, emphasizing crisis-proofing of economies,
"second-generation" reforms, and policies addressing inequality and
social issues. As noted, in spite of Williamson's
reservations, the term Washington Consensus has been used more broadly to
describe the general shift towards free market policies that followed the
displacement of Keynesianism in the 1970s. In this broad sense the
Washington Consensus is sometimes considered to have begun at about 1980.
Many commentators see the consensus, especially if interpreted in the broader
sense of the term, as having been at its strongest during the 1990s. Some have
argued that the consensus in this sense ended at the turn of the century, or at
least that it became less influential after about the year 2000. More
commonly, commentators have suggested that the Consensus in its broader sense
survived until the time of the 2008–2009 global financial crisis. Following the
strong intervention undertaken by governments in response to market
failures, a number of journalists, politicians and senior officials from
global institutions such as the World Bank began saying that the Washington
Consensus was dead. These included former British Prime Minister Gordon
Brown, who following the 2009 G-20 London summit, declared "the old
Washington Consensus is over". Williamson was asked by The Washington
Post in April 2009 whether he agreed with Gordon Brown that the Washington
Consensus was dead. He responded: It depends on what one means by the
Washington Consensus. If one means the ten points that I tried to outline, then
clearly it's not right. If one uses the interpretation that a number of
people—including Joe Stiglitz, most prominently—have foisted on it, that it
is a neoliberal tract, then I think it is right.
After the 2010 G-20 Seoul summit announced that it had achieved agreement
on a Seoul Development Consensus, the Financial Times editorialized that "Its
pragmatic and pluralistic view of development is appealing enough. But the
document will do little more than drive another nail into the coffin of a
long-deceased Washington consensus." Context
Many countries have endeavored to implement varying components of the
reform packages, with implementation sometimes imposed as a condition for
receiving loans from the IMF and World Bank. The results of these reforms are
much debated. Some critics focus on claims that the reforms led to
destabilization. Some critics have also blamed the Washington Consensus for
particular economic crises such as the Argentine economic crisis, and for
exacerbating Latin America's economic inequalities. Criticism of the
Washington Consensus has often been dismissed as socialism and/or
anti-globalism. While these philosophies do criticize these policies, general
criticism of the economics of the consensus is now more widely
established, such as that outlined by US scholar Dani Rodrik, Professor of
International Political Economy at Harvard University, in his paper Goodbye
Washington Consensus, Hello Washington Confusion?.
The institutions that formed the consensus started softening their
insistence on these policies in the 2000s largely due to political pressures
surrounding globalization, but any reference of these ideas as a consensus
essentially ended in the wake of the 2008 global financial crisis, as market
fundamentalism lost favour. Though, it should be noted, that most of the core
specific policies are still generally regarded favourably, but the policies
have come to be viewed as not preventing nor alleviating acute economic crises.
This is perhaps most notable in the work of the IMF with South Korea to create a
new sort of intervention program to the one that South Korea was forced to
accept during the Asian Financial Crisis of the late 1990s. That intervention,
which was heavily grounded in the Washington Consensus, was hailed at the
time for stopping the "Asian Contagion" but eventually the program came to be
seen more skeptically. Williamson himself has summarized the
overall results on growth, employment and poverty reduction in many countries
as "disappointing, to say the least". He attributes this limited impact to three
factors: the Consensus per se placed no special emphasis on mechanisms for
avoiding economic crises, which have proved very damaging; the reforms—both
those listed in his article and, a fortiori, those actually
implemented—were incomplete; and the reforms cited were insufficiently